Conceptualising productivity measurement from a classical perspective
DOI:
https://doi.org/10.13133/2037-3643/18513Keywords:
Productivity measurement, Input-Output analysis, Vertical (Hyper-)Integration, Prices of productionAbstract
Productivity seems an obvious concept: output per unit of input. Yet, when contextualised within alternative views of production and distribution, challenges across attempts at measuring it are far from trivial. The aim of this paper is to present and discuss some foundational concepts for measuring productivity from a classical perspective, as opposed to a more traditional standpoint. A key distinction is made between measuring productivity from the expenditure (or physical quantities) side and quantifying profitability from the value added (or income) side. Productivity is opposed to productiveness and commodity reduction is contrasted to price aggregation. After critically discussing the traditional standpoint of total factor productivity growth, this paper conceptually discusses the method of (growing) subsystems and the computation of production prices as analytical and empirical devices for measuring productivity and profitability in a multisectoral economy.
References
Aulin-Ahmavaara P. (1999), “Effective rates of sectoral productivity change”, Economic Systems Research, 11(4), pp. 349-363.
Baldone S. (1980), “Fixed capital in Sraffa’s theoretical scheme”, in Pasinetti L.L. (ed.), Essays on the Theory of Joint Production, London and Basingstoke: The Macmillan Press Ltd.
Balk B.M. (2010), “An assumption-free framework for measuring productivity change”, Review of Income and Wealth, 56(1), pp. 224-256.
Bródy A. (1970), Proportions, Prices and Planning — A Mathematical Restatement of the Labor Theory of Value, Budapest: Akademiai Kiado.
Brondino G. (2019), “Productivity growth and structural change in China (1995–2009): A subsystems analysis”, Structural Change and Economic Dynamics, 49, pp. 183-191.
Buccellato C. (1990), “Input-Output analysis, technological change and relations between industry and services”, Economic Systems Research, 2(1), pp. 53-63.
Cas A. and Rymes T.K. (1991), On concepts and measures of multifactor productivity in Canada, 1961-1980, Cambridge: Cambridge University Press.
Casler S.D. and Gallatin M.S. (1997), “Sectoral contributions to total factor productivity: Another perspective on the growth slowdown”, Journal of Macroeconomics, 19(2), pp. 381-393.
Coelli T.J., Prasada Rao D.S., O’Donnell C.J. and Battesse G.E. (2005), An Introduction to Efficiency and Productivity Analysis, Second Edition, New York: Springer.
De Juan O. and Febrero E. (2000), “Measuring productivity from vertically integrated sectors”, Economic Systems Research, 12(1), pp. 65-82.
Degasperi M. and Fredholm T. (2010), “Productivity accounting based on production prices”, Metroeconomica, 61(2), pp. 267-281.
Dietzenbacher E., Hoen A.R. and Los B. (2000), “Labour productivity in Western Europe 1975-1985: An intercountry, interindustry analysis”, Journal of Regional Science, 40(3), pp. 425-452.
Elmslie B. and Milberg W. (1996), “The productivity convergence debate: a theoretical and methodological reconsideration”, Cambridge Journal of Economics, 20, pp. 153-182.
Ferretti F. (2008), “Patterns of technical change: a geometrical analysis using the wage-profit rate schedule”, International Review of Applied Economics, 22(5), pp. 565-583.
Flaschel P. (2010), Topics in Classical Micro- and Macroeconomics — Elements of a Critique of Neoricardian Theory, Berlin and Heidelberg: Springer-Verlag.
Fredholm T. and Zambelli S. (2009), “Measuring Structural and Technological Change from Technically Autarkic Subsystems — A Study of Danish Industries 1966-2005”, Working Papers from Department of Economics, Politics and Public Administration, Aalborg University.
Galatin M. (1988), “Technical change and the measurement of productivity in an input-output model”, Journal of Macroeconomics, 10(4), pp. 613-632.
Garbellini N. (2010), Essays on the Theory of Structural Economic Dynamics — Growth, Technical Progress, and Effective Demand, PhD thesis, Università Cattolica del Sacro Cuore, Milan, Italy.
Garbellini N. and Wirkierman A.L. (2014), “Productivity Accounting in Vertically (Hyper-) integrated Terms: Bridging the Gap between Theory and Empirics”, Metroeconomica, 65(1), pp. 154-190.
Garbellini N. and Wirkierman A.L. (2023), “The Solow-Pasinetti debate on productivity measurement: Review and reformulation”, Structural Change and Economic Dynamics, 65(June), pp. 438-447.
Garegnani P. (1983), “The classical theory of wages and the role of demand schedules in the determination of relative prices”, The American Economic Review, 73(2), pp. 309-313.
Garegnani P. (1987), “Surplus approach to value and distribution”, in Eatwell J., Milgate M. and Newman P. (eds), The New Palgrave: A Dictionary of Economics, London: Macmillan.
Gilibert G. (1977), Quesnay. La costruzione della “macchina della prosperità”, Milan: Etas Libri.
Gilibert G. (1987), “Revenue, gross and net”, in Eatwell J., Milgate M., and Newman P. (eds), The New Palgrave: A Dictionary of Economics, London: Macmillan.
Gilibert G. (2003), “The equations unveiled: Sraffa’s price equations in the making”, Contributions to Political Economy, 22, pp. 27-40.
Gilibert G. (2006), “The man from the moon: Sraffa’s upside-down approach to the theory of value”, Contributions to Political Economy, 25, pp. 35-48.
Gilibert G. (2010), “L’economia politica considerata come la madre di tutte le scienze”, in Bonifati G. and Simonazzi A. (eds), Il Ritorno dell’Economia Politica — Saggi in ricordo di Fernando Vianello, Roma: Donzelli Editore, pp. 153-168.
Gossling W.F. (1972), Productivity Trends in a Sectoral Macro-Economic Model, London: Input-Output Publishing.
Gossling W.F. (1974), “Measuring the productivity of direct plus indirect factor inputs of agriculture for the trading economy: Some suggestions for some British indices”, Journal of Agricultural Economics, XXV (3), pp. 335-340.
Gossling W.F. and Dovring F. (1966), “Labor productivity measurement: The use of subsystems in the interindustry approach and some approximating alternatives”, Journal of Farm Economics, 48(2), pp. 369-377.
Gowdy J.M. and Miller J.L. (1990), “Harrod-Robinson-Read measures of primary input productivity: Theory and evidence from U.S. data”, Journal of Post Keynesian Economics, 12(4), pp. 591-604.
Gupta S. and Steedman I. (1971), “An input-output study of labour productivity in the British economy”, Oxford Bulletin of Economics and Statistics, 33, pp. 21-34.
Hagemann H. (1987), “Capital goods”, in Eatwell J., Milgate M. and Newman P. (eds), The New Palgrave: A Dictionary of Economics, London: Macmillan.
Hague D.C. (1961), “Summary Record of the Debate”, in Hague D.C. (ed.), The Theory of Capital — Proceedings of a Conference held by the International Economic Association, London: Macmillan.
Han Z. and Schefold B. (2006), “An empirical investigation of paradoxes: reswitching and reverse capital deepening in capital theory”, Cambridge Journal of Economics, 30, pp. 737-765.
Harberger A.C. (1998), “A vision of the growth process”, The American Economic Review, 88(1), pp. 1-32.
Hejl L., Kyn O. and Sekerka B. (1967), “Price calculations”, Czechoslovak Economic Papers, 8, pp. 61-81.
Hodgskin T. ([1825] 1969), Labour Defended against the Claims of Capital; or the Unproductiveness of Capital Proved with Reference to the Present Combinations amongst Journeymen. New York: Augustus M. Kelley.
Hsieh C.T. (1999), “Productivity growth and factor prices in East Asia”, The American Economic Review, 89(2), pp. 133-138.
Jorgenson D.W. and Griliches Z. (1967), “The explanation of productivity change”, The Review of Economic Studies, 34(3), pp. 249-283.
Krelle W. (1977), “Basic facts in capital theory. Some lessons from the controversy in capital theory”, Revue d’Economie Politique, 87(2), pp. 282-329.
Kurz H.D., Dietzenbacher E. and Lager C. (1998), “General introduction”, in Kurz H.D., Dietzenbacher E. and Lager C. (eds), Input-Output Analysis — Volume I, Cheltenham: Edward Elgar.
Kurz H.D. and Salvadori N. (2005a), “Removing an ‘insuperable obstacle’ in the way of an objectivist analysis: Sraffa’s attempts at fixed capital”, European Journal of the History of Economic Thought, 12(3), pp. 493-523.
Kurz H.D. and Salvadori N. (2005b), “Representing the production and circulation of commodities in material terms: On Sraffa’s objectivism”, Review of Political Economy, 17(3), pp. 413-441.
Kyn O., Sekerka B. and Hejl L. (1967), “A model for the planning of prices”, in Feinstein C.H. (ed.), Socialism, Capitalism and Economic Growth, Cambridge: Cambridge University Press, pp. 101-124.
Leontief W.W. (1937), “Interrelation of prices, output, savings, and investment”, The Review of Economics and Statistics, 19(3), pp. 109-132.
Leontief W.W. (1951), The Structure of American Economy, 1919-1939, 2nd. edition, New York: Oxford University Press.
Leontief W.W. (1953), “Structural change”, in Studies in the Structure of the American Economy — Theoretical and Empirical Explorations in Input- Output Analysis (pp. 17-52), New York: Oxford University Press.
Leontief W.W. (1967), “An alternative to aggregation in input-output analysis and national accounts”, The Review of Economics and Statistics, 49(3), pp. 412-419.
Leontief W.W. (1986), “Technological change, prices, wages, and rates of return on capital in the U.S. economy”, in Leontief W.W. (ed.), Input-Output Economics — Second Edition (pp. 392-417), New York: Oxford University Press.
Leontief W.W. ([1928] 1991), “The economy as a circular flow”, Structural Change and Economic Dynamics, 2(1), pp. 181-212.
Lippi M. (1979), Value and Naturalism in Marx. London: NLB.
Liverani M. (1998), Uruk — The first city, London: Equinox.
Marengo L. (1992), “The demand for intermediate goods in an input-output framework: A methodological note”, Economic Systems Research, 4(1), pp. 49-52.
Marx K. ([1867] 1976). Capital — A Critique of Political Economy, volume I, London: Penguin Books.
Marx K. ([1885] 1978). Capital — A Critique of Political Economy, volume II, London: Penguin Books.
Marzi G. (1982), “Variabili distributive e produttività in un analisi intersettoriale dell’economia italiana”, Ricerche Economiche, XXXVI (4), pp. 489-513.
Marzi G. (1993), “Production prices and wage-profit curves: An evaluation of the empirical results”, Working Paper 94.03, Dipartimento di Economia Politica e Aziendale, Università degli Studi di Milano.
Marzi G. (1994), “Vertically integrated sectors and the empirics of structural change”, Structural Change and Economic Dynamics, 5(1), pp. 155-175.
Marzi G. and Varri P. (1977), Variazioni di Produttività nell’Economia Italiana: 1959-1967 — Un’applicazione dello schema di Sraffa. Bologna: Società Editrice Il Mulino.
Mas-Colell A. (1989), “Capital theory paradoxes: Anything goes”, in Feiwel G.R. (ed.), Joan Robinson and Modern Economic Theory (pp. 505-520), London: Macmillan.
Meade D.S. (2010), “Why real value added is not my favorite concept”, Studies on Russian Economic Development, 21(3), pp. 249-262.
Metcalfe J.S. (2002), “Knowledge of growth and the growth of knowledge”, Journal of Evolutionary Economics, 12(1), pp. 3-15.
Michl T.R. (1991), “Wage-profit curves in US manufacturing”, Cambridge Journal of Economics, 15, pp. 271-286.
Milberg W. and Elmslie B. (1992), “Technical change in the corporate economy: A vertically integrated approach”, in Milberg W. (ed.), The Megacorp & Macrodynamicsi (pp. 101-132), London: M.E. Sharpe.
Milgate M. and Stimson S.C. (2009), After Adam Smith — A Century Of Transformation In Politics And Political Economy, Princeton and Oxford: Princeton University Press.
Ochoa E.M. (1986), “An input-output study of labour productivity in the U.S. economy, 1947-72”, Journal of Post Keynesian Economics, 9(1), pp. 111-137.
Ozol C. (1984), “Parable and realism in production theory: The surrogate wage function”, The Canadian Journal of Economics, 17(2), pp. 353-368.
Ozol C. (1991), “The surrogate wage function and capital: Theory and measurement”, The Canadian Journal of Economics, 24(1), pp. 175-191.
Pasinetti L.L. (1959), “On concepts and measures of changes in productivity”, The Review of Economics and Statistics, 41(3), pp. 270-286.
Pasinetti L.L. (1963), A multi-sector model of economic growth. Cambridge: King’s College.
Pasinetti L.L. (1973), “The notion of vertical integration in economic analysis”, Metroeconomica, 25, pp. 1-29.
Pasinetti L.L. (1977), “On ‘non-substitution’ in production models”, Cambridge Journal of Economics, 1(4), pp. 389-394.
Pasinetti L.L. (1981), Structural Change and Economic Growth — A Theoretical Essay on the Dynamics of the Wealth of Nations, Cambridge: Cambridge University Press.
Pasinetti L.L. (1986), “Sraffa’s circular process and the concept of vertical integration”, Political Economy: Studies in the Surplus Approach, 2(1), pp. 3-16.
Pasinetti L.L. (1988), “Growing subsystems, vertically hyper-integrated sectors and the labour theory of value”, Cambridge Journal of Economics, 12(1), pp. 125-34.
Pasinetti L.L. (1990), “Reply”, in Bharadwaj, K. and Schefold, B. (eds), Essays on Piero Sraffa — Critical Perspectives on the Revival of Classical Theory, London: Unwin Hyman.
Peterson W. (1979), “Total factor productivity in the UK: A disaggregated analysis”, in Patterson, K. D. and Schott, K. (eds), The measurement of Capital. Theory and Practice, London: Macmillan.
Rampa G. (1981a), “The concept and measurement of productivity in an input-output framework”, Working Papers, No. 18, University of Cambridge.
Rampa G. (1981b), “Concetto e misura della produttività in uno schema input-output”, Annali della Fondazione Luigi Einaudi, XV, pp. 107-127.
Rampa G. and Rampa L. (1982), “Sul mutamento tecnologico nell’economia italiana, 1959-1975: Un’analisi input-output”, Ricerche Economiche, XXXVI (4), pp. 303-341.
Reich U.P. (2001), National Accounts and Economic Value — A Study in Concepts. New York: Palgrave.
Ricardo D. ([1817] 1951), “On the principles of political economy and taxation”, in Sraffa P. and Dobb M.H. (eds), The Works and Correspondence of David Ricardo, Volume 1, Cambridge: Cambridge University Press.
Salter W.E.G. (1966), Productivity and Technical Change. Cambridge: Cambridge University Press.
Schefold B. (1982), “Book review of Pasinetti’s structural change and economic growth”, Kyklos, XXXV (3), pp. 548-550.
Schefold B. (1989), Mr Sraffa on Joint Production and Other Essays. London: Unwin Hyman.
Sekerka B., Kyn O. and Hejl L. (1970), “Price systems computable from input-output coefficients”, in Carter A.P. and Bródy A. (eds), Contributions to Input-Output Analysis (pp. 183-203), Amsterdam - London: North-Holland Publishing Company.
Seyfried M. (1988), “Productivity growth and technical change”, in Ciaschini M. (ed.), Input-Output Analysis — Current Developments, London: Chapman and Hill.
Siniscalco D. (1982), “Il sistema produttivo: Analisi per industrie e subsistemi”, Ricerche Economiche, XXXVI (4), pp. 475-488.
Smith A. ([1776] 1994), An Inquiry into the Nature and Causes of the Wealth of Nations, edited, with an introduction, notes, marginal summary, and enlarged index by Edwin Cannan, New York: The Modern Library.
Solow R.M. (1957), “Technical change and the aggregate production function”, The Review of Economics and Statistics, 39(3), pp. 312-320.
Sraffa P. (1960), Production of Commodities by Means of Commodities, Cambridge: Cambridge University Press.
ten Raa T. (1994), “On the methodology of input-output analysis”, Regional Science and Urban Economics, 24(1), pp. 3-25.
Vincent L.A. (1962), “Une nouvelle méthode de calcul de la productivité intégrale du travail”, Études et conjoncture, 17(1), pp. 55-70.
Wirkierman A.L. (2012), Productivity Analysis from a Classical Perspective: Theory of Measurement and Measurement of Theory, PhD thesis, Università Cattolica del Sacro Cuore, Milan, Italy.
Wirkierman A.L. (2022a), “Productivity homogenisation trends of six advanced industrial economies: A vertically hyper-integrated approach”, Structural Change and Economic Dynamics, 61, pp. 495-511.
Wirkierman A.L. (2022b), “Structural dynamics in the era of smart technologies”, in Kurz H.D., Schutz M., Strohmaier R. and Zilian S. (eds), The Routledge Handbook of Smart Technologies: An Economic and Social Perspective (pp. 269-289), London: Routledge.
Wolff E.N. (1985), “Industrial composition, interindustry effects, and the U.S. productivity slowdown”, The Review of Economics and Statistics, 67(2), pp. 268-277.
Wolff E.N. (1994), “Productivity measurement within an input-output framework”, Regional Science and Urban Economics, 24(1), pp. 75-92.
Downloads
Published
How to Cite
Issue
Section
License
Copyright (c) 2024 Ariel Luis Wirkierman
This work is licensed under a Creative Commons Attribution-NonCommercial-NoDerivatives 4.0 International License.