La solitudine dell’agente rappresentativo: eterogeneità e interazione per una nuova macroeconomia (The solitude of the representative agant: Heterogeneity and interaction for a new macroeconomics)

Authors

  • Giovanni Dosi Sapienza University of Rome
  • Andrea Roventini Scuola Superiore Sant’Anna, Pisa, OFCE Sciences Po, Sophia-Antipolis

DOI:

https://doi.org/10.13133/2037-3643_72.287_7

Keywords:

macroeconomics, economic policy, agent based models

Abstract

La Grande Recessione è stata un esperimento naturale per la macroeconomica, mostrando l’inadeguatezza della teoria dominante basata sui modelli DSGE. La macroeconomia dovrebbe considerare l’economia come un sistema complesso in evoluzione, cioè come un’ecologia popolata da agenti eterogenei, che interagiscono fuori dall’equilibrio cambiando continuamente la struttura stessa del sistema. Quindi, la macroeconomia non può ridursi alle scelte micro di un agente rappresentativo, ma le complesse interazioni tra gli agenti portano all’emergenza di nuovi fenomeni e strutture gerarchiche a livello macro. Questo è alla base dei modelli ad agenti eterogenei, che offrono una nuova metodologia per modellare economie complesse “dal basso”, con microfondazioni in linea con l’evidenza empirica.

The Great Recession was a natural experiment for macroeconomics, showing the inadequacy of the predominant theoretical framework grounded on DSGE models. Macroeconomics should consider the economy as a complex evolving system, i.e. as an ecology populated by heterogeneous agents, whose far-from-equilibrium interactions continuously change the structure of the system. This in turn implies that macroeconomics cannot be shrunk to representative-agent micro, but agents’ complex interactions lead to emergence of new phenomena and hierarchical structure at the macro level. This is what is taken into account by agent-based models, which provide a novel way to model complex economies from the bottom-up, with sound empirically-based microfoundations.

JEL codesB41, B50, E32, E52

References

Akerlof G.A. (2002), “Behavioral Macroeconomics and Macroeconomic Behavior”, American Economic Review, 92 (3), pp. 411-433.

Akerlof G.A. (2007), “The Missing Motivation in Macroeconomics”, American Economic Review, 97 (1), pp. 5-36.

Akerlof G.A. e Yellen J.L. (1985), “A Near-Rational Model of the Business Cycles, with Wage and Price Inertia”, Quarterly Journal of Economics, 100 (suppl.), pp. 823-838.

Anderson P.W. (1972), “More is Different”, Science, 177 (4047), pp. 393-396.

Bak P., Chen K., Scheinkman J.A. e Woodford M. (1992), “Aggregate Fluctuations from Indipendent Sectoral Shocks: Self-Organize Criticality”, NBER Working Paper, n. 4241, Washington (DC): National Bureau of Economic Research.

Bernanke B.S. (2004), “The Great Moderation”, discorso tenuto al meeting dell’Eastern Economic Association, Washington (DC), 20 febbraio, disponibile alla URL: https://www.federalreserve.gov/boarddocs/speeches/2004/20040220/

Blanchard O. e Brancaccio E. (2019), “Pensare un’alternativa. Dialogo tra Olivier Blanchard e Emiliano Brancaccio”, Micromega, 2, pp. 7-30; (cfr. anche Blanchard O. e Brancaccio E., “Crisis and Revolution in Economic Theory and Policy: A Debate”, Review of Political Economy, published online 6 August).

Blanchard O.J. e Galí J. (2007), “Real Wage Rigidities and the New Keynesian Model”, Journal of Money, Credit and Banking, 39 (s1), 35-65.

Blanchard O. e Summers L. (2019), “Ripensare la politica macroeconomica: evoluzione o rivoluzione?”, Moneta e Credito, 72 (287), pp. 171-195 (orig. “Rethinking Stabilization Policy: Evolution or Revolution?”, NBER Working Paper, n. 24179, Cambridge (MA): National Bureau of Economic Research.

Brancaccio E. (2017), Anti-Blanchard. Un approccio comparato allo studio della macroeconomia, Milano: Franco Angeli.

Brancaccio E. (2019), “Sulle condizioni per una ‘rivoluzione’ della teoria e della politica economica”, Moneta e Credito, 72 (287), pp. 197-206.

Caballero R.J. (2010), “Macroeconomics after the Crisis: Time to Deal with the Pretense-of-Knowledge Syndrome”, Journal of Economic Perspectives, 24 (4), pp. 85-102.

Dawid H. e Delli Gatti D. (2018), “Agent-Based Macroeconomics”, in Hommes C. e LeBaron B. (a cura di), Handbook of Computational Economics, vol. IV (pp. 63-156), Amsterdam: Elsevier.

De Long J.B. (2000), “The Triumph of Monetarism?”, Journal of Economic Perspectives, 14 (1), pp. 83-94.

Dosi G. e Roventini A. (2017), “Agent-Based Macroeconomics and Classical Political Economy: Some Italian Roots”, Italian Economic Journal: a Continuation of Rivista Italiana degli Economisti and Giornale degli Economisti, 3 (3), pp. 261-283.

Dosi G. e Roventini A. (2019), “More is Different … and Complex! The Case for Agent-Based Macroeconomics”, Journal of Evolutionary Economics, 29 (1), pp. 1-37.

Dosi G. e Virgillito M.E. (2017), “In Order to Stand up You Must Keep Cycling: Change and Coordination in Complex Evolving Economies”, Structural Change and Economic Dynamics, 21 giugno, https://doi.org /10.1016/j.strueco.2017.06.003

Dosi G., Fagiolo G. e Roventini A. (2010), “Schumpeter Meeting Keynes: A Policy-Friendly Model of Endogenous Growth and Business Cycles”, Journal of Economic Dynamics and Control, 34 (9), pp. 1748-1767.

Dosi G., Fagiolo G., Napoletano M., Roventini A. e Treibich T. (2015), “Fiscal and Monetary Policies in Complex Evolving Economies”, Journal of Economic Dynamics and Control, 52 (marzo):166-189.

Dosi G., Napoletano M., Roventini A. e Treibich T. (2016), “The Short- and Long-Run Damages of Fiscal Austerity: Keynes beyond Schumpeter”, in Stiglitz J. e Guzman M. (a cura di), Contemporary Issues in Macroeconomics (pp. 79-100), Basingstoke: Palgrave Macmillan.

Dosi G., Pereira M.C., Roventini A. e Virgillito M.E. (2017), “When More Flexibility Yields More Fragility: The Microfoundations of Keynesian Aggregate Unemployment”, Journal of Economic Dynamics and Control, 81 (agosto), pp. 162-186.

Dosi G., Pereira M.C., Roventini A. e Virgillito M.E. (2018a), “The Effects of Labour Market Reforms upon Unemployment and Income Inequalities: an Agent-Based Model”, Socio-Economic Review, 16 (4), pp. 687–720

Dosi G., Pereira M.C., Roventini A. e Virgillito M.E. (2018b), “Causes and Consequences of Hysteresis: Aggregate Demand, Productivity and Employment”, Industrial and Corporate Change, 27 (6), pp 1015-1044.

Edelman G.M. e Gally J.A. (2001), “Degeneracy and Complexity in Biological Systems”, Proceedings of the National Academy of Sciences, 98 (24), pp. 13763-13768.

Fagiolo G e Roventini A. (2017), “Macroeconomic Policy in DSGE and Agent-Based Models Redux: New Developments and Challenges Ahead”, Journal of Artificial Societies & Social Simulation, 20(1), pp. 1-37.

Fagiolo G., Guerini M., Lamperti F., Moneta A. e Roventini A. (2019), “Validation of Agent-Based Models in Economics and Finance”, in Beisbart C. e Saam N.J. (eds.), Computer Simulation Validation. Fundamental Concepts, Methodological Frameworks, Philosophical Perspectives (pp. 763-787), Cham: Springer International Publishing.

Farmer D.J. e Foley D. (2009), “The Economy Needs Agent-Based Modeling”, Nature, 460, pp. 685686.

Fukuyama F. (1992), The End of History and the Last Man, London: Penguin.

Galí J. e Gertler M. (2007), “Macroeconomic Modelling for Monetary Policy Evaluation”, Journal of Economic Perspectives, 21 (4), pp. 25-46.

Gigerenzer G. e Brighton H. (2009), “Homo Heuristicus: Why Biased Minds Make Better Inferences”, Topics in Cognitive Science, 1 (1), pp. 107-143.

Greenwald B. e Stiglitz J. (1993a), “Financial Market Imperfections and Business Cycles”, Quarterly Journal of Economics, 108 (1), pp. 77-114.

Greenwald B. e Stiglitz J. (1993b), “New and Old Keynesians”, Journal of Economic Perspectives, 7 (1), pp. 23-44.

Haldane A.G. e Turrell A.E. (2019), “Drawing on Different Disciplines: Macroeconomic Agent-Based Models”, Journal of Evolutionary Economics, 29 (1), pp. 39-66.

Hahn F. (1991), “The Next Hundred Years”, Economic Journal, 101 (404), pp. 47-50.

Kirman A.P. (1989), “The Intrinsic Limits of Modern Economic Theory: The Emperor Has No Clothes”, Economic Journal, 99 (395), pp. 126-139.

Kirman A.P. (1992), “Whom or What Does the Representative Individual Represent?”, Journal of Economic Perspectives, 6 (2), pp. 117-136.

Kirman A.P. (2014), “Is It Rational to Have Rational Expectations?”, Mind and Society, 13 (1), pp. 29-48.

Kirman A.P. (2016), “Ants and Nonoptimal Self-Organization: Lessons for Macroeconomics”, Macroeconomic Dynamics, 20 (2), pp. 601-621.

Klamer A. (1984), The New Classical Macroeconomics Conversations with the New Classical Economists and Their Opponents, Brighton: Wheatsheaf Books.

Knight F. (1921), Risk, Uncertainty and Profits, Chicago: Chicago University Press.

Krugman P. (2011), “The Profession and the Crisis”, Eastern Economic Journal, 37 (3), pp. 307-312.

LeBaron B. e Tesfatsion L. (2008), “Modeling Macroeconomies as Open-Ended Dynamic Systems of Interacting Agents”, American Economic Review, 98 (2), pp. 246-250.

Leijonhufvud A. (1968), On Keynesian Economics and the Economics of Keynes: A Study in Monetary Theory, New York: Oxford University Press.

Lindè S.F., Smets F. e Wouters R. (2016), “Challenges for Central Banks’ Macro Models”, in Taylor J.B. e Uhlig H. (eds.), Handbook of Macroeconomics, vol. II (pp. 2185-2262), Amsterdam: North Holland.

Lucas R.E.J. (2003), “Macroeconomic Priorities”, American Economic Review, 93(1):1–14.

Mankiw G.N. e Romer D. (eds.) (1991), New Keynesian Economics, Cambridge: MIT Press.

Prigogine I. (1980), From Being to Becoming: Time and Complexity in the Physical Sciences, San Francisco: Freeman.

Romer P. (2016), “The Trouble with Macroeconomics” American Economic Review, 20 (10), pp. 1-20.

Stiglitz J. (2011), “Rethinking Macroeconomics: What Failed, and How to Repair It”, Journal of the European Economic Association, 9 (4), pp. 591-645.

Published

2019-09-06

Issue

Section

Special issue: Crisis and revolutions in economic theory